Tuesday, November 20, 2018

22 Days in Paul Krugman's Masterclass (Day 3) (The Horrific Lesson)

Lesson 3 in Paul Krugman's Masterclass is 7 minutes and 40 seconds long.

It is 1 minute and 51 seconds shorter than Lesson 2 but on a theoretical level much greater damage is done than in yesterday's lesson.

In this lesson, Krugman introduces Ricardo's rent theory as a foundation of economics. This is a disastrous start.

I will let Murray Rothbard explain the problem here. From Rothbard's Classical Economics:
The price of corn, in its turn, is determined according to Ricardo's famous
theory of rent. Rent served as the linchpin of the Ricardian system. For,
according to Ricardo's rather bizarre theory, only land differed in quality. Labour, as we have seen, was assumed to be uniform, and therefore wage rates are uniform... 
Rent, in Ricardo's phrase, is payment for the 'use of the original and
indestructible powers of the soil'. This hints at a productivity theory, and
indeed Ricardo did see that more fertile and productive lands earned a higher
rent. But unfortunately, as Schumpeter put it, Ricardo then 'embarks upon his
detour'. In the first place, Ricardo made the assumption that at any moment
the poorest land in cultivation yields a zero rent. He concluded from that
alleged fact that a given piece of land earns rent not because of its own
productivity, but merely because its productivity is greater than the poorest,
zero-rent, land under cultivation...

Hence, to Ricardo, rent is purely a differential, and Land A earns rent
solely because of its differential productivity compared to Land B, the
zero-rent land in cultivation...

And since the quantity of labour needed to produce corn keeps rising
as more and more inferior lands are put into production, this means that the
cost of producing corn and hence the price of corn keep rising over time.
And, paradoxically, while rent keeps rising over time, it remains zero at the
margin, and therefore without any impact on costs.

There are many flaws in this doctrine. In the first place, even the poorest
land in cultivation never earns a zero rent, just as the least productive piece of
machinery or worker never earns a zero price or wage. It does not benefit any
resource owner to keep his resource or factor in production unless it earns a
positive rent. The marginal land, or other resource, will indeed earn less of a
rent than more productive factors, but even the marginal land will always
earn some positive rent, however small.

Second, apart from the zero-rent problem, it is simply wrong to think that
rent, or any other factor return, is caused by differentials. Each piece of land,
or unit of any factor, earns whatever it produces; differentials are simple
arithmetic subtractions between two lands, or other factors, each of which
earns a positive rent of its own. The assumption of zero rent at the margin
allows Ricardo to obscure the fact that every piece of land earns a productive
rent, and allows him to slip into the differential as cause...

[I]n discussing the rise in cost of producing corn, Ricardo reverses
cause and effect. Ricardo states that increasing population 'obliges' farmers
to work land of inferior quality and then causes a rise in its price. But as any
utility theory analyst would realize, the causal chain is precisely the reverse:
when the demand for corn increases, its price would rise, and the higher price
would lead farmers to grow corn on higher-cost land. But this realization, of
course, eliminates the Ricardian theory of value and with it the entire Ricardian
system...

Ricardo's differential rent theory has been widely hailed as the precursor
of the neoclassical law of diminishing returns, which the neoclassicals were
supposed to have generalized from land to all factors of production. But this
is wrong, since the law of diminishing returns applies to increasing doses of a
factor to homogeneous units of other, logically fixed, factors - in this case
land. But the whole point of Ricardo's differential rent theory is that his areas
of land are not homogeneous at all, but varying in a spectrum from superiority
to inferiority. Therefore the law of diminishing returns - as grasped by
Turgot and rediscovered by the neoclassicals - simply does not apply.
Then Krugman goes completely off the rails by his telling of the "Parable of the Baby-Sitting Co-Op".

I have discussed in the past the problems with this "parable":
In 1998, Krugman wrote in Slate of an earth shattering experience:
Twenty years ago I read a story that changed my life. I think about that story often; it helps me to stay calm in the face of crisis, to remain hopeful in times of depression, and to resist the pull of fatalism and pessimism.
The story was the babysitting co-op story of which he writes:
The Capitol Hill co-op adopted one fairly natural solution. It issued scrip--pieces of paper equivalent to one hour of baby-sitting time. Baby sitters would receive the appropriate number of coupons directly from the baby sittees. This made the system self-enforcing: Over time, each couple would automatically do as much baby-sitting as it received in return. As long as the people were reliable--and these young professionals certainly were--what could go wrong?
It is important to understand what is going on here. In a moment Krugman is going to liken this babysitter co-op to the economy. But this is far from the case of what the co-op is, on any scale. In actuality, what is going on here is barter. You watch my kids, I'll watch your kids, with scrip inserted to make sure there is a balance between watching and leaving off. 

So the first important thing to understand is that in Krugman's little world there is no money! Money is a medium of exchange you use in nearly all daily transactions, not a piece of script that can only be used for babysitting purposes. So he is trying to justify the printing of money using a model where there is no money! 

Let's move on. Krugman writes:
Well, it turned out that there was a small technical problem. Think about the coupon holdings of a typical couple. During periods when it had few occasions to go out, a couple would probably try to build up a reserve--then run that reserve down when the occasions arose. There would be an averaging out of these demands. One couple would be going out when another was staying at home. But since many couples would be holding reserves of coupons at any given time, the co-op needed to have a fairly large amount of scrip in circulation.

Now what happened in the Sweeneys' co-op was that, for complicated reasons involving the collection and use of dues (paid in scrip), the number of coupons in circulation became quite low. As a result, most couples were anxious to add to their reserves by baby-sitting, reluctant to run them down by going out. But one couple's decision to go out was another's chance to baby-sit; so it became difficult to earn coupons. Knowing this, couples became even more reluctant to use their reserves except on special occasions, reducing baby-sitting opportunities still further.

In short, the co-op had fallen into a recession.
First, let's consider this "small technical problem". Krugman doesn't go into details, but for some reason there is an obvious taking away of script from some of the participants. The dues sound like some kind of a tax. The rational conclusion would be, "Hey taxes are bad, they are taking from some and giving to others. If you do it at a high enough rate, you are going to collapse the system". The script system, because of these tax/dues, appears to have pretty much collapsed the co-op. But what is cute is that Krugman doesn't call this tax/dues caused collapse a tax/dues caused collapse, he calls it a recession.

It's Krugman getting really mentally disorderly. These scripts, I emphasize again, are barter tools, not money. The scripts do not have an exchange ratio against all products the way money does, i.e. money is about prices. The scripts simply reflect a call on babysitting services. That's it. A recession is about changing prices. The stock market collapses in a recession, housing prices collapse, prices are too high for some products, causing fewer sales resulting in businesses laying off employees and sometimes failing. How is any of this action reflected in Krugman's babysitting story? The answer is that it is not.

Yet, Krugman plows along with his model and says that the issuing of more calls on babysitting services is like printing money. But, it is an entirely different thing. If the money supply somehow dropped, prices would adjust downward so that the economy could function. In Krugman's model with script, when the script declines because of dues/taxes, there is no mechanism to adjust the economy, because we are not talking about an economy or a medium of exchange, we are talking only about a script good for one hour of babysitting. Print more calls for babysitting services and, duh, you will get more demand for babysitting services. If you print more money, prices adjust through out the economy having only distorting impact on the economy that favors those who get the new money first. 

Bottom line: Krugman's babysitting model is so poorly constructed and has so little to do with the real economy that one has to think that it's easy to understate the depth of his incomprehension.
-RW 

Links to discussions of all Krugman's Masterclass lessons are here.




2 comments:

  1. Sorry, Mr. Wenzel, but despite your poor opinion of Krugman, he is a genius! From your post today, it appears that Krugman is reading aloud old columns of his, and charging people $90 to watch him do it. Probably more lucrative than doing an audio book -- "markets in everything" etc. etc.

    ReplyDelete
  2. Indeed. The genius of Krugman is being paid so well for so little of value.

    ReplyDelete