Wednesday, March 30, 2011

The Fed Explains Why It Is Great

The American banking system is always on the edge of crisis because of the Federal Reserve System.

For all practical purposes, the United States has one bank, the Federal Reserve with a bunch of branches that are treated with different degrees of respect. Some are treated rudely, while others in the eyes of the Fed, can do no wrong.

One support method the Fed uses to protect its favored "branches" is the discount rate. At its blog site today, the New York Fed attempts to justify this Fed tool that serves to prop up the entire convoluted Federal Reserve System.

We can see a key problem with the Fed as overlord, current banking system by taking a look at the first paragraph of a post by NY Fed bloggers applauding themselves. The bloggers write:

 ...the basic rationale for [the discount window] is that circumstances can arise, such as bank runs and panics, when even fundamentally sound banks cannot raise liquidity on short notice
But how can a "fundamentally sound" bank ever face a liquidity problem? A liquidity problem comes about only because the Federal Reserve system encourages (partly through the discount window) the mismatch between time structure of money deposited at the bank and money loaned out. A liquidity problem simply means that a bank may have loaned out money for 30 years, when a depositor has the right to withdraw such funds after 30 days. Banks aren't too concerned about this mismatch, since they know they can always go to the Fed to get money (via the discount window) if  withdrawals are occurring that are greater than cash the bank has on hand or can borrow from other sources.

In other words, it is the Fed's backstop that encourages the mismatch between length of deposits and length of loans. Without this backstop, banks would never create such a mismatch. It would be too risky for them (And this is aside from the moral implications of promising to pay in 30 days some funds on money that has been loaned out for years.)

Without a Fed, banks taking in short-term money would loan it out for short-terms and would make long-term loans with money that depositors had agreed to keep on deposit for the long term. End of liquidity problems for banks and the start of truly fundamentally sound banks.

The NY Fed bloggers go on to discuss the various ways the discount rate should be implemented by what the Fed bloggers think are somehow "fundamentally sound" banks, when the deposit versus loan time structure of these banks is more distorted than a Dali painting.

The final sentence of the final paragraph on the NY Fed post is probably most telling:
Admittedly, the existence of the discount window may create some moral hazard, but of course, the Federal Reserve limits moral hazard by restricting discount window access to depository institutions that are closely regulated and supervised by federal banking authorities.
Bottom line: The Fed holds all the cards over its "branches", get out of line and they will suddenly see you as an insolvent bank versus a bank with just a liquidity problem. The bloggers admit that some economists don't think the Fed can even technically tell the difference, if they wanted to:
Some observers contend that central bankers are no better equipped to distinguish illiquid but solvent banks than are private investors.
It's a rigged game, boom, busts, bank failures versus just a liquidity crisis, Ben Bernanke just strokes his beard and decides what's what. (After consulting with his controls, of course.)

(Thanks 2 Bob English for pointing this post out to me and who also writes: Must be a coincidence this is being published one day ahead of tomorrow's court-ordered fulfillment of Bloomberg's FOIA request.)

5 comments:

  1. Prior to seeing the note at the bottom, I had the same thought running through my head from the first sentence of the post: seems like convenient timing they've come out with a post attempting to rationalize the discount window just a day before they've been court ordered to disclose which banks would have been insolvent in its absence.

    ReplyDelete
  2. A better name for the discount window would be 'window for fundamentally sound banks with liquidity problems'.

    That last sentence ("Admittedly, the existence of...") seemed at first a howler, but when I thought about it for a moment longer, I realized how insidious it is. Any bank that disdains the discount window is likely to be at a competitive disadvantage, for it will have to maintain higher average excess reserves or to take fewer risks than banks that use it as a backstop.

    An early step toward unrigging the banking industry, and eventually getting rid of the FRS itself, will have to be closing that discount window and prohibiting the FRS from using other means to substitute for its function.

    ReplyDelete
  3. All banks are equally insolvent, but some are more equal than others...

    ReplyDelete
  4. Fractional reserve banking is fraud, plain and simple.

    ReplyDelete
  5. It's safe to assume that any nation endorses a ponzi-scheme for it's sovereign currency, views both citizens and bankers as assets. The FED does not care if their domestic policy creates instability and pain for the peons unknowingly supporting the elite. Even in a Bust cycle, their living standards don't have to change.

    ReplyDelete