As for the turnaround, it is totally a Ben Bernanke produced event, so it will be as manipulated of a "recovery" as one can get, followed by severe inflation. In other words, the economy will look good, maybe, for the first two quarters of 2011
and that's about it. I explained this to a D.C. insider who got it right away and said, "So it's going to be a 'sugar high' recovery." That nails it exactly.
As we come close to the end of the first two quarters that I wrote about back in December 2010, this is todays top headline at CNBC:
'Sugar High That Has Buoyed US Economy Is Wearing Out'CNBC then quotes Mike Riddell, a fund manager at M&G Investments in London:
"It seems that almost every bit of data about the health of the US economy has disappointed expectations recently," said Riddell, in a note sent to CNBC on Wednesday.Bottom line, most analysts are trend followers who forecast out the trend of the former month. They have no theory to understand the twists and turns of the economy (Or they hold a convulted Keynesian theory that must confuse them even more).
Right now, the economy is in an extremely vulnerable state that can result in it turning in a number of different directions. And few understand what even needs to be monitored. Whether there is a QE3,or not, is about number 5 on the list of monetary factors I am looking it. What happens to excess reserves, required reserves, seasonally adjusted money growth versus non-seasonally adjusted growth, the Fed funds rate versus the interest paid on excess reserves are all more important than if there is a QE3 (I monitor all these factors in the EPJ Daily Alert).
There are countervailing forces among these factors right now which make things trickier to forecast than ever. If there ever needs to be a time to monitor money factors very closely, it is the present. Otherwise, it is whipsaw city. All those watching Bernanke for an indication about QE3 are looking in the wrong direction. Bernanke is a mad scientist, who understands maybe half of the new tools he has created. As I wrote a week or so ago in an EPJ Daily Alert, Bernanke's QE2 is a scam. What you have to watch is the factors I outlined above, and the chief economist of financial research at the New York Fed, James McAndrews, has written an entire piece exposing Bernanke's quantitative easing nonsense and what needs to be monitored to understand what is going on in the economy. I reproduce from the the May 23, EPJ Daily Alert :
In one of the most difficult environments, ever, to understand what is going on in the economy, most analysts aren't even looking at the correct data. It's going to get real tricky out there and the trend followers will get smashed real hard. Next up, they have no idea how hard price inflation is going to hit in the second half. Buckle your seat belt.
Long term EPJ Daily Alert readers know that I have been something of a
lone wolf advising that what needs to be watched is excess reserves
since Bernanke started paying interest on them rather than just Fed
assets. QE2 was kept largely under control from creating too much new
money because most of the funds went into excess reserves.
To my total amazement, the chief economist of financial research at
the New York Fed, James McAndrews, put out a report Monday, detailing
what has been my position right along, that QE2 did not have a greater
impact because the reserves went into excess reserves and they did so
because the Fed is paying interest on excess reserves.
I find that I am in nearly complete agreement with McAndrews
explanation, with the one caveat that he seems to believe that
reserves can be kept out of the system by controlling the rate paid on
excess reserves. True enough they can, technically. But the rate on
excess reserves is now 0.25%, if rates go back up to pre-crisis levels
of around 5%, I find it hard to believe that the Fed will boost rates
quick enough to the 5% level to stop the flow of some reserves into
the system. How many and at what speed will be the issue.
With that significant warning, McAndrews correctly makes the point
that QE2 was not that inflationary, but he neglects to emphasise that
now that QE2 is over, the excess reserve overhang remains and it has
the potential to become highly inflationary, even if there isn't a
QE3.
I reproduce McAndrew's full report below because of its major
significance in helping understand how Bernanke's new "tools" have
changed the game and monitoring monetary policy using pre-Bernanke
monetary watch posts, such as the assets on the Fed's balance sheet,
will lead to incorrect analysis.
Here's McAndrews:
Will the Federal Reserve’s Asset Purchases Lead to Higher Inflation?
By Jamie McAndrews
A common refrain among critics of the Federal Reserve’s large-scaleasset purchases (“LSAPs”) of Treasury securities is that the Fed issimply printing money to purchase the assets, and that this moneygrowth will lead to much higher inflation. Are those charges accurate?In this post, I explain that the Fed’s asset purchases do notnecessarily lead to higher money growth, and that the Fed’s ability(since 2008) to pay interest on banks’ reserves provides a criticalnew tool to constrain future money growth. With this innovation, anincrease in bank reserves no longer mechanically triggers a series ofresponses that could lead to excessive money growth and higherinflation.
To follow my argument, think of the relationship between Fed assetpurchases and inflation in terms of a pipeline with several sections.The first section of the pipeline relates to reserve balances. Whenthe Fed purchases assets, it pays for the purchases by creatingreserve balances. These reserve balances can put pressure on latersections of the pipeline—the money supply and inflation rate. Now,however, there is a new valve—interest on reserves—that provides anoutlet from the pipeline to a reservoir, enabling policymakers toreduce the pressure from reserves.
The Old Pipeline View: Why Fed Asset Purchases Will Generate Higher Inflation
There are three parts to the argument that Fed asset purchases willlead to much higher inflation. First, there is the connection betweenFed asset purchases and reserves. When the Fed buys assets from thepublic, it pays for them by electronically crediting banks’ accountsat the Fed with reserves. Second, there is a connection betweenreserves and money growth. When banks’ reserve balances increase, theycan use these additional reserves to make more loans to households andbusinesses—an outcome that can lead to further growth in the broadmoney supply in the economy. Third, there is a connection betweenhigher credit and money growth and inflation. For example, excessivecredit expansion can bring on higher money growth, excess demandpressures, and overheating in the economy, which in turn can raiseinflation expectations and increase the inflation rate.
My view is that this description of the pipeline between Fed assetpurchases and inflation is accurate except for the connection betweenreserves and money growth. I’ll show that asset purchases to date havenot led to unusually rapid growth in the money supply, and I’ll alsoexplain why a large amount of reserves need not induce rapid growth inmoney over time.
A Useful Review: Money and Reserves
Money is usually defined as a generally accepted medium of exchange,used to purchase a good or service or to retire a debt. Money takesmany forms in modern society, such as cash, deposit accounts at banks,shares in money market mutual funds, and savings account balances andother liabilities issued by banks, credit unions, and thrifts. TheFederal Reserve tracks two measures of money—the monetary aggregatesM1 and M2. Currency and demand deposits at banks are the largestindividual components of both M1 and M2, but M2—the broadermeasure—also includes savings deposits, small time deposits, andretail money funds (for fuller definitions, see Federal ReserveStatistical Release H.6).
Reserves are balances that commercial banks hold in accounts atFederal Reserve Banks. When the Fed purchases assets from the public,it pays for them by electronically crediting funds to banks’ reservebalances at the Fed. Reserves are part of the monetary base, anothermonetary aggregate tracked by the Federal Reserve. The monetary baseconsists mainly of currency and reserves (for a fuller definition, seeFederal Reserve Statistical Release H.3). In contrast to currency anddemand deposits at banks, which can be held by anyone, accounts atFederal Reserve Banks can be held only by banks and a few otherspecial institutions such as the government-sponsored enterprisesFannie Mae and Freddie Mac.
An important change in the nature of reserve balances occurred onOctober 9, 2008, when banks began to earn interest on the reservebalances they held at Federal Reserve Banks. As we shall see, thistransformation of reserves from a non-interest-bearing asset (likecurrency) to an interest-bearing asset is significant.
With these concepts understood, we can now address our mainquestion: Will the Fed’s asset purchases lead to inflation?
How Do Fed Purchases Affect the Money Supply?
My counterargument to those who contend that Fed asset purchases willgenerate higher inflation will focus on the second section of thepipeline—the possible link between reserves and growth in money. Whenthe Fed purchases a security from the public, it first credits theseller’s bank with reserves. In turn, the bank credits the seller’schecking account with a deposit. As long as the seller does notwithdraw the deposit, the money supply, measured by either M1 or M2,will have increased by the exact amount of the Fed’s purchase. It isimportant to note that in the example just given, the money supplyincreased because of the behavior of all parties: the Fed in creatingreserves, the bank in creating deposits, and the depositor inmaintaining the deposit.
In other circumstances, the increase in the money supply followinga purchase by the Fed can be either less than or greater than theamount of the Fed’s asset purchase. If the depositors in the economyare deleveraging, that is, if they choose to repay debts (such asprevious loans) after the bank credits their accounts with deposits,the increase in the money supply following a Fed purchase can be lessthan the amount of the Fed purchase. As a depositor repays a debt itowes to a bank, the bank’s loans and deposits decrease. If depositorsare repaying loans at the same time that deposits are increasing as aresult of asset purchases by the Fed, then the net effect could be adecrease in deposits, if the repayment of loans exceeds the assetpurchases.
Alternatively, if bank customers demand new loans from banks, andbanks use the reserves created by the Fed to extend loans tocustomers, then the money supply could grow by more than the amount ofthe Fed purchase.
What has, in fact, happened with the money supply since thebeginning of the LSAP programs in late 2008? As measured by the growthin M1, money growth has been less than the amount of the Fed’spurchases (see chart)—a development that is consistent with thedeleveraging, or net repayment of loans, by bank customers that hasoccurred since late 2008. The Federal Reserve Bank of New York’sQuarterly Report on Household Debt and Credit for the first quarter of2011 indicated that “as of March 31, 2011, total consumer indebtednesswas $11.5 trillion, a reduction of $1.03 trillion (8.2 percent) fromits peak level at the close of 2008Q3.” So deleveraging by U.S.consumers has been substantial during the period of the LSAPs.
The New Pipeline View: Why a Surge in Money Growth Isn’t Inevitable
As of early 2011, there was little evidence of aggressive lending bybanks, and the recent behavior of the broader money supply, economicactivity, and inflation suggests that money growth has not beenexcessive. Nevertheless, there are commentators who view the highlevel of reserves resulting from the Fed’s asset purchases as“inflation tinder.” Won’t those reserve balances inevitably lead tohigh money growth at some point, as banks seek to lend them out? HereI can clearly state that the answer is no.
The basis for my answer is that the introduction of interest onreserves has altered the linkage between reserves and money growth.Before banks were eligible to earn interest on their reserve balances,they had strong incentives to avoid holding “excess reserves”—reservesin excess of the amount they are required to hold by regulation. Highlevels of excess reserves in the old regime would be expected togenerate a high growth rate of loans, and consequently high moneygrowth whenever the banks’ risk-adjusted expected return on loans waspositive.
In the new regime, the Fed can vary the rate of interest onreserves to directly affect banks’ incentives to lend out excessreserves. For example, a bank holding excess reserves will not have aneconomic incentive to lend out those reserves if the risk-adjustedexpected return on the loan is below the rate the bank earns on itsreserve balances. In terms of our analogy to a pipeline, the rate ofinterest paid on reserves now acts as a valve, reducing the pressurethat Fed purchases might place on banks to increase lending andthereby spur money growth. When higher interest rates are paid onreserves, the reserves are put in a sort of reservoir, relieving aflow that could ultimately generate higher inflation.
In its December 14, 2010, statement, the Federal Open MarketCommittee (FOMC) indicated that it “will employ its policy tools asnecessary to support the economic recovery and to help ensure thatinflation, over time, is at levels consistent with its mandate.” TheFOMC may choose future policies that result in faster or slower moneygrowth, but the presence of large amounts of reserve balances onbanks’ balance sheets by itself does not inevitably commit the FOMC toa high future money growth policy. Instead, if Fed policymakersbelieve that it is preferable to rein in bank lending and moneygrowth, they can raise the rate of interest paid on reserves andthereby dampen banks’ incentives to lend out reserve balances.
Alright, Doc! I'm counting on you (and Gary North) to give me a heads up on when to sidestep from my gold/silver bet. You convinced me, that you are monitoring the right metrics.
ReplyDeleteIt should be a bumpy, exciting ride!
Bob,
ReplyDeleteWhat if the Fed just keeps a healthy spread, in favor of reserves, between excess reserves and the Fed funds rate? Could this keep the excess reserves tied up indefinitely?
All this talk of "reserves" is total nonsense. Its a reserveless system. Why have reserves of digital credit? Whats the purpose of that? Its all digital, its all fake, there are no reserves! The non-federal reserveless syndicate. Its going down. Ron Paul 2012!!!
ReplyDelete"What if the Fed just keeps a healthy spread, in favor of reserves, between excess reserves and the Fed funds rate? Could this keep the excess reserves tied up indefinitely? "
ReplyDeleteNo. At some point, banks will see their money is better placed in alternative investments that offer higher returns, particularly as price inflation continues (boosting prices like those of stocks.) The Fed could try offer more to beat this out but it'll end up paying more for it, exacerbating inflationary pressures further if it prints money to do so. Bob Murphy has an article on this that's worth reading.
Do you have the Bob Murphy link Inquisitor? I'd love to read that.
ReplyDelete